欢迎来到冰豆网! | 帮助中心 分享价值,成长自我!
冰豆网
全部分类
  • IT计算机>
  • 经管营销>
  • 医药卫生>
  • 自然科学>
  • 农林牧渔>
  • 人文社科>
  • 工程科技>
  • PPT模板>
  • 求职职场>
  • 解决方案>
  • 总结汇报>
  • 党团工作>
  • ImageVerifierCode 换一换
    首页 冰豆网 > 资源分类 > DOCX文档下载
    分享到微信 分享到微博 分享到QQ空间

    国家没有区位优势时的外商直接投资竞争外文翻译.docx

    • 资源ID:4510465       资源大小:24.18KB        全文页数:7页
    • 资源格式: DOCX        下载积分:3金币
    快捷下载 游客一键下载
    账号登录下载
    微信登录下载
    三方登录下载: 微信开放平台登录 QQ登录
    二维码
    微信扫一扫登录
    下载资源需要3金币
    邮箱/手机:
    温馨提示:
    快捷下载时,用户名和密码都是您填写的邮箱或者手机号,方便查询和重复下载(系统自动生成)。
    如填写123,账号就是123,密码也是123。
    支付方式: 支付宝    微信支付   
    验证码:   换一换

    加入VIP,免费下载
     
    账号:
    密码:
    验证码:   换一换
      忘记密码?
        
    友情提示
    2、PDF文件下载后,可能会被浏览器默认打开,此种情况可以点击浏览器菜单,保存网页到桌面,就可以正常下载了。
    3、本站不支持迅雷下载,请使用电脑自带的IE浏览器,或者360浏览器、谷歌浏览器下载即可。
    4、本站资源下载后的文档和图纸-无水印,预览文档经过压缩,下载后原文更清晰。
    5、试题试卷类文档,如果标题没有明确说明有答案则都视为没有答案,请知晓。

    国家没有区位优势时的外商直接投资竞争外文翻译.docx

    1、国家没有区位优势时的外商直接投资竞争外文翻译本科毕业论文(设计)外文翻译外文题目:Competition for foreign direct investment when countries Are not sure of site values 出 处:International Review of Economics and Finance 作 者:Koray Kiymaz and Leon Taylor 原文: Competition for foreign direct investment when countries are not sure of site valuesAbs

    2、tract The fiscal tug-of-war between two countries to play host to a foreign-owned firm is like a Nash game. Suppose that the countries are not sure how much the firm values the sites that they offer to it. Also suppose that the countries fashion their expectation of site value by assigning the same

    3、likelihood to each value that they deem possible. Then, if they are quite unsure about site values, they will offer small subsidies to the firm. If they are pretty sure about site values,they will offer large subsidies. Hereis the intuition behind theresults: When a country is unsure about the value

    4、 of its site, it is also unsure if a stingy offer will drive the firm to its rival, so it may take the chance and make a stingy offer rather than a generous one. 1. Introduction Governments often vie for a footloose firm by offering tax cuts or subsidies.Analyses of such a contest usually assume tha

    5、t its participants know full well its circumstances. In reality, its participants usually know little. For instance, government officials must guess at how much a firm values a site when they have no competitive bids to refer to. That is usually the case when government recruits industry because the

    6、 lack of local land buyers is what spurs the government to seek buyers elsewhere.The governments guess about the value of a site will affect its offer of incentives to a potential buyer. But if the government knows little about the value of its own site, then it is likely to know little about the va

    7、lue of a site elsewhere that the firm could occupy. The governments guess about that other site will also affect its offer of incentives. How these guesses will affect its offer is a subtle question, particularly when it must counter the offer of another government that guesses.The question is criti

    8、cal to the early stage of a site search, when the firm decides where to go. In this stage, the firm discloses stark details of its project to a few governments and solicits their preliminary bids. (Hood and Young, 1985, found that this strategy was typical in the searches of automotive firms for for

    9、eign sites.) Among the governments, the firm will later pick one with which to negotiate in earnest. Until then, governments game more with one another than with the firm, which carefully conceals its poker hand.This paper analyzes that early stage of a site search. The key characteristic of the sta

    10、ge is that the firm keeps the governments in the dark about the values that it attaches to their industrial sites. The paper considers how the resulting uncertainty of governments affects their offers of incentives to the firm.One can obtain sharp answers to this question because one can reasonably

    11、presume that the governments are sure about a few things. In particular, one can presume that each government is sure of how the other would counter its offer, for it is likely that the governments have gamed before, perhaps in the conduct of foreign relations. We need not presume, however, that eit

    12、her government is sure of how the firm would react to their offers.In general, our analysis applies to economic competition between governments at the local, state, or national level. In particular, it will motivate the mathematics by addressing contests between countries for foreign direct investme

    13、nt (FDI).We favor the international application for its timeliness. Through the 1970s and until the late 1980s, analysts posited that the foreign firm and the host treated one another warily, like monopolies. Vernons 1971 model of bilateral monopoly dominated the literature, and the shift of bargain

    14、ing power from oil extractors to oil producers dominated the news. In recent years, however, Third World hosts have vied for foreign firms by offering subsidies to them as well as by lifting restrictions on them.Over time, models of competition that can apply to countries vying for foreigndirect inv

    15、estment have come to stress the aggressive tactics of the potential hosts in pursuing firms: the construction of infrastructure to entice them; the willingness to reopen negotiations with them or even to bid in an auction for them. Doyle and van Wijnbergen (1994) analyzed a firm that procures tax ho

    16、lidays by bargaining with one Government at a time.Bond and amuelson(1986)took a similar tack,and Andersson(1991) examined how sequential bargaining affects the distribution of gains from foreign direct investment between host and firm. Black and Hoyt (1989) model a firm That negotiates with several

    17、 governments at the same time and then choose sits locationonce and for all. In a new tradition, King and Welling (1992) examine a firm that can relocate. In each of two periods, the firm conducts an auction between two regions bidding for its plant. King et al. (1993) extend the model so that gover

    18、nments can build infrastructure first and then bid in an auction for a firm.Several of these models allow for uncertainty.For example,Black and Hoy texamine uncertainty about how much the firm can produce in one site rather than another, and King and Welling consider uncertainty over the sunk cost o

    19、f building the plant. The contribution that our article tries to make to this literature, however, focuses on he uncertainty of potential hosts about the relative value of their plant sites.That a few countries now compete for a foot loose firm is the main point of departure for our analysis of unce

    20、rtainty. In particular, we branch from the work that treats, as paramount, the uncertainty that affects bargaining between the firm and its chosen host.We branchfrom thiswork becauseunlessitis enrichedby moretheorysome of its main implications may no longer describe so well the world that we know.Fo

    21、r instance, Vernon (1971) considers a poor country that discovers a deposit of raw material. The country does not know how to exploit the deposit, so it sells exploitation rights to a foreign-owned firm, and it does so cheaply because it must compensate the firm for taking a risk. The host invites i

    22、n the firm partly to learn how it exploits the raw material. Once the host learns, it will claim for itself the profits from future exploits. Vernones que theory thus implied that, over time, as poor coun-tries learned more of the technology of the foreign firms on their soil, they would take over m

    23、ore of them.By the late 1980s, however, the wave of nationalizations in the Third World had ebbed, even though there were still plenty of firms to seize, as Andersson found in 1991. Where, for all its power, might Vernonesque theory have gone astray? We suspect that a missing piece of the puzzle is

    24、that hosts now compete for a firm when they are unsure of its location costs. Seizing a firm today can hurt the chances of a potential host in the competition for another firm tomorrow if the host does not know how much to offer the sought-after firm to offset the increase in its cost expecta-tion o

    25、f costs that would result from the earlier seizure.Generally, the host cannot be sure of how much to offer the firm to locate in its borders, largely because it cannot precisely estimate the political, social, and cultural costs that the firm would face in foreign production. Such costs do not fit c

    26、omfortably beneath the measuring rod of money. While such intangible costs may vary with the firms level of physical capital, they do not typically vary with its scale of production. And so the analysis will treat political,social,and culturalcosts as intangible fixed costs.Firms appear to shun nati

    27、ons that are politically or socially instable. Stevens (1969) as well as Schneider and Frey (1985) have provided statistical evidence of this point, and Pfeffermann (1992) has drawn upon World Bank experience. Since such fixed costs as political instability matter to the firm, they also matter to th

    28、e host. In particular, thefirms estimate of intangible fixed costs matters to the host, yet it has trouble inferring this cost estimate, in large part because it lacks the firms industrial experience.For instance,the firm knows more than prospective hosts about the value that the plant and equipment

    29、 would add to its operations. The firm can thus estimate the cost to it of a seizure of capital more precisely than prospective hosts can.We investigate how two countries compete for a firm when they are unsure of itsfixed costs of location. Given this uncertainty, each country determines the size o

    30、f The subsidy that it would offer the firm to occupy its site.This determination is strategic, since the country considers the subsidy that its rival would offer the firm. Although The countries share the same beliefs about the values of their sites,the sites themselves differ. To describe the sites

    31、 as differentiated products offered by countries, we draw upon industrial organization models, especially that of Perloff and Salop (1985). Section 2 begins by analyzing competitive offers of subsidies by countries that are sure of site values. This case yields a benchmark by which to judge the effe

    32、cts of uncertainty on incentivesthe case that we consider next. The aim of the analysis is to guide an empirical study, and Section 3 considers empirical implications that one may test.2. Conclusions and reflections This simple model of competition between two host countries for a foreign firm sugge

    33、sts that large subsidies are extraneous for the country with the larger market orthe better infrastructure. That finding is broadly consistent with statistical work pub-lished by Root and Ahmed (1978). They carried out a multiple discriminant analysis of three groups of developing countries. The groups differed from one an


    注意事项

    本文(国家没有区位优势时的外商直接投资竞争外文翻译.docx)为本站会员主动上传,冰豆网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。 若此文所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知冰豆网(点击联系客服),我们立即给予删除!

    温馨提示:如果因为网速或其他原因下载失败请重新下载,重复下载不扣分。




    关于我们 - 网站声明 - 网站地图 - 资源地图 - 友情链接 - 网站客服 - 联系我们

    copyright@ 2008-2022 冰点文档网站版权所有

    经营许可证编号:鄂ICP备2022015515号-1

    收起
    展开